CHAPTER XVIII
The "Wealth of Nations"
1
89.
Guild Apprenticeships
2
The policy of Europe occasions a very important inequality
in the whole of the advantages and disadvantages of the different
employments of labor and stock, by restraining the competition
in some employments to a smaller number than might
otherwise be disposed to enter into them.
The exclusive privileges of corporations are the principal
means it makes use of for this purpose.
The exclusive privilege of an incorporated trade necessarily
restrains the competition, in the town where it is established,
to those who are free of the trade. To have served an apprenticeship
in the town, under a master properly qualified, is commonly
the necessary requisite for obtaining this freedom. The
by-laws of the corporation regulate sometimes the number of
apprentices which any master is allowed to have, and almost
always the number of years which each apprentice is obliged to
serve. The intention of both regulations is to restrain the competition
to a much smaller number than might otherwise be disposed
to enter into the trade. The limitation of the number
of apprentices restrains it directly. A long term of apprenticeship
restrains it more indirectly, but as effectually, by increasing
the expense of education.
In Sheffield no master cutler can have more than one apprentice
at a time, by a by-law of the corporation. In Norfolk and
Norwich no master weaver can have more than two apprentices,
under pain of forfeiting five pounds a month to the king. No
master hatter can have more than two apprentices anywhere in
England, or in the English plantations, under pain of forfeiting
five pounds a month, half to the king, and half to him who shall
sue in any court of record. Both these regulations, though they
have been confirmed by a public law of the kingdom, are evidently
dictated by the same corporation spirit which enacted
the by-law of Sheffield. The silk weavers in London had scarcely
been incorporated a year when they enacted a by-law, restraining
any master from having more than two apprentices at a
time. It required a particular act of parliament to rescind this
by-law.
Seven years seem anciently to have been, all over Europe,
the usual term established for the duration of apprenticeships
in the greater part of incorporated trades. All such incorporations
were anciently called universities; which indeed is the
proper Latin name1 for any incorporation whatever. The
university of smiths, the university of tailors, etc., are expressions
which we commonly meet with in the old charters of
ancient towns. . . .
The property which every man has in his own labor, as it is
the original foundation of all other property, so it is the most
sacred and inviolable. The patrimony of a poor man lies in
the strength and dexterity of his hands; and to hinder him
from employing this strength and dexterity in what manner he
thinks proper without injury to his neighbor, is a plain violation
of this most sacred property. It is a manifest encroachment
upon the just liberty both of the workman, and of those who
might be disposed to employ him. As it hinders the one from
working at what he thinks proper, so it hinders the others from
employing whom they think proper. To judge whether he is
fit to be employed, may surely be trusted to the discretion of
the employers whose interest it so much concerns. The affected
anxiety of the lawgiver, lest they should employ an improper
person, is evidently as impertinent as it is oppressive.
The institution of long apprenticeships can give no security
that insufficient workmanship shall not frequently be exposed
to public sale. When this is done it is generally the effect of
fraud, and not of inability; and the longest apprenticeship can
give no security against fraud. Quite different regulations are
necessary to prevent this abuse. The sterling mark upon plate,
and the stamps upon linen and woolen cloth, give the purchaser
much greater security than any statute of apprenticeship. He
generally looks at these, but never thinks it worth while to
inquire whether the workmen had served a seven years’ apprenticeship.
The institution of long apprenticeships has no tendency to
form young people to industry. A journeyman who works by
the piece is likely to be industrious, because he derives a benefit
from every exertion of his industry. An apprentice is likely to
be idle, and almost always is so, because he has no immediate
interest to be otherwise. In the inferior employments, the
sweets of labor consist altogether in the recompense of labor.
They who are soonest in a condition to enjoy the sweets of it,
are likely soonest to conceive a relish for it, and to acquire the
early habit of industry. A young man naturally conceives an
aversion to labor, when for a long time he receives no benefit
from it. The boys who are put out apprentices from public
charities are generally bound for more than the usual number of
years, and they generally turn out very idle and worthless. . . .
Long apprenticeships are altogether unnecessary. The arts,
which are much superior to common trades, such as those of
making clocks and watches, contain no such mystery as to
require a long course of instruction. The first invention of
such beautiful machines, indeed, and even that of some of the
instruments employed in making them, must, no doubt, have
been the work of deep thought and long time, and may justly be
considered as among the happiest efforts of human ingenuity.
But when both have been fairly invented and are well understood,
to explain to any young man, in the completest manner,
how to apply the instruments and how to construct the machines,
cannot well require more than the lessons of a few weeks: perhaps
those of a few days might be sufficient. In the common
mechanic trades, those of a few days might certainly be sufficient.
The dexterity of hand, indeed, even in common trades,
cannot be acquired without much practice and experience. But
a young man need practice with much more diligence and attention,
if from the beginning he wrought as a journeyman, being
paid in proportion to the little work which he could execute,
and paying in his turn for the materials which he might sometimes
spoil through awkwardness and inexperience. His education
would generally in this way be more effectual, and always
less tedious and expensive. The master, indeed, would be a
loser. He would lose all the wages of the apprentice, which he
now saves, for seven years together. In the end, perhaps, the
apprentice himself would be a loser. In a trade so easily learnt
he would have more competitors, and his wages, when he came
to be a complete workman, would be much less than at present.
The same increase of competition would reduce the profits of
the masters as well as the wages of workmen. The trades, the
crafts, the mysteries, would all be losers. But the public would
be a gainer, the work of all artificers coming in this way much
cheaper to market.
1 Adam Smith, ,
edited by J. E. T. Rogers. 2 vols. 2d edition. Oxford, 1880. Clarendon Press.
2 Smith, , bk. i, ch. 10, pt. 2.
1Universitas.